布鲁盖尔研究所-央行数字货币的增值:来自欧元区的观点(英)-2023.6-19页

VIP专免
3.0 Susu2024 2024-07-23 91 16 528.19KB 20 页 免费
侵权投诉
Maria Demertzis (maria.
demertzis@bruegel.org) is a
Senior Fellow at Bruegel
Catarina Martins (catarina
martins@bruegel.org) is a
Research Analyst at Bruegel
Executive summary
Different jurisdictions have set out dierent reasons for creating central bank digital
currencies (CBDCs). Some countries, particularly those with already-operational CBDCs for
retail purposes, aim to to promote nancial inclusion. But in countries where most citizens
have access to nancial services, central banks are interested in CBDCs as an aspect of the
increasing digitalisation of nance.
Central banks could also choose to use CBDCs to guarantee in full citizen’s holdings
(currently, deposits in commercial bank are only partially guaranteed), but this would
trigger major changes in the nancial system in terms of the role of commercial banks in
intermediation and the role of at money. So far, central banks have not opted to go this way.
In the euro area, consumers have multiple payment options and a very ecient retail
payments system. e currency enjoys high levels of trust and is not challenged by the
emergence of private currencies, such as Bitcoin, or by the risk that cash, a monetary systems
anchor, will disappear. erefore, creating a CBDC for retail purposes in the euro area oers
little obvious value added, at least for the foreseeable future.
However, there is a strong case for building a CBDC that banks could use for cross-border
wholesale purposes (ie with other currencies). Wholesale CBDCs could revolutionise the way
that cross-border, cross-currency payments are made for two reasons.
1. Cross-border payments are currently slow and inecient. Pilot projects have shown that
wholesale payments with CBDCs can generate substantial time and cost savings.
2. Any two central banks that have operational wholesale CBDCs could settle
transactions between themselves. is would be very dierent from the current
system, as most settlements today are done via the dollar (and then the euro)
infrastructure and use correspondent banks.
The euro area and the United States would have to consider carefully from a geopolitical
perspective how wholesale CBDCs might aect their global economic standing. By
developing a CBDC for wholesale purposes, the European Union would be able to contribute
to developing the global standard.
Recommended citation
Demertzis, M. and C. Martins (2023) ‘e value added of central bank digital currencies: a
view from the euro area, Policy Brief 13/2023, Bruegel
Policy Brief
Issue n˚13/23 | June 2023 The value added of central
bank digital currencies: a view
from the euro area
Maria Demertzis and Catarina Martins
2Policy Brief | Issue n˚13/23 | June 2023
1 Introduction
Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs), a digital equivalent of cash, are increasingly gaining
traction. At least 114 jurisdictions, representing 95 percent of global GDP, are at some stage of
developing a CBDC1. In 11 countries, CBDCs are now a reality and operate in parallel to their
physical equivalent. But it is not necessarily easy for the consumer to understand the dier-
ence between a euro in coin or note form and a digital euro.
A good starting point in identify the benets of CBDCs is to understand the problem
that cannot be solved through the increasing range of digital payment options provided by
the private sector, and which therefore requires the states intervention. is is important in
explaining why the taxpayer might be asked to nance the creation of a CBDC.
We argue that CBDCs do have added value, but this is not the same for every country. In
countries with high levels of nancial exclusion and where there is a lack of modern and reli-
able digital payment systems, a CBDC can facilitate access to payments for many people. But
in countries with ample payment solutions and where nancial exclusion is a second-order
problem, the justication is dierent. Central banks worry that as nance becomes increas-
ingly digitalised, two things might happen: rst physical cash, the anchor of any nancial
system, will be displaced, and second, private currencies will become popular. Both could
reduce the monopoly of sovereign money. Central banks fear this would compromise their
ability to maintain monetary and nancial stability.
CBDCs will have a dual purpose, just like their physical equivalent: for retail purposes,
typically by consumers and small businesses to make daily payments, representing a small
part of total payments; and for wholesale (ie bulk) purposes by banks and other nancial
institutions, either domestically or cross border. In the euro area, most eorts to date have
focused on how to develop a retail CBDC. Only recently2 has there been also an attempt to
advance thinking on the wholesale aspects as well.
On the retail side, the arguments for a digital euro put forward by the European Central
Bank revolve around the speed of digitalisation of nance and the notion of strategic auton-
omy. e prospect of nance becoming predominantly and eventually even exclusively digital
threatens the existence of sovereign money and compromises the role of its guardian, the
central bank. e ECB also argues that a big part of all payments is managed by foreign play-
ers, who collect sensitive information about EU citizens. A pan-European payment method
that is very close to cash would help reduce this vulnerability. It would also help homogenise
payments in the euro area and, given easier access, may help promote the international role
of the euro.
However, these reasons, understandable as they might be, do not make a compelling case
for a retail digital euro, at least for now. ere is no imminent threat that digitalisation will
undermine the role of the physical euro. And there are easier ways, like through regulation,
to promote the creation of a uniformly-accepted digital instant payment method in the EU,
without having the taxpayer nance a CBDC. Meanwhile, Europe’s vulnerability arising from
foreign players being present in the payment sphere is a very delicate argument. Does the EU
want to create European payment players at the expense of competition?
Finally, the euro has acquired a very stable international role, second to, and quite far
from, the dollar. At best, a digital equivalent can only expand the euros international appeal
at the margins. Other factors that pertain to a more integrated and well-governed European
economy would advance more signicantly its international acceptability. ere are also
several technical choices, including limits on the amount of digital euros that any citizen can
1 See the Atlantic Council central bank digital currency tracker: https://www.atlanticcouncil.org/cbdctracker/.
2 See European Central Bank press release of 28 April 2003, ‘Eurosystem to explore new technologies for wholesale
central bank money settlement’, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2023/html/ecb.pr230428~6a59f44e41.
en.html.
Central bank digital
currencies do have
added value, but this
is not the same for
every country
3Policy Brief | Issue n˚13/23 | June 2023
hold, or the fact that these deposits will not be remunerated, that also prevent the greater
international use of the euro. In addition, the Eurosystem has a very fast and ecient retail
payment system and can still nd eciency gains within the current system. All these make
the case for a digital euro even less attractive.
However, the EU and the global nancial system can really benet from developing whole-
sale CBDCs for making payments outside the euro area. is can generate eciency gains
for all payments made outside the EU. In our view, the creation of CBDCs globally has the
potential of revolutionising cross-border payments. For now, one reason why the dollar is the
currency of choice globally is because it oers the infrastructure via which any two parties can
settle a transaction. Any two countries that have CBDCs will have in principle the ability to
settle transactions between them, bypassing the current dollar-based system.
Before this could happen however, there would have to be a commonly agreed global
standard on how to design and use CBDCs. is is a signicant barrier as it requires mutual
recognition of legal systems and agreement on economic and technical design issues (BIS,
2022). Global governance will be a major obstacle to this revolution and the euro area and the
United States would have to consider carefully how their economic standing globally would
be aected.
For example, current sanctions on Russia mean that countries that want to continue
economic relations with Russia cannot do so in dollars or euros. Mutually accepted CBDCs
between any two countries could allow them to continue trading and therefore bypass sanc-
tions. is reduces the need for the dollar infrastructure in international settlements and,
importantly, raises the threshold for returning to the dollar when the option presents itself in
the future. International nancial fragmentation encourages the development of CBDCs and
may be part of the explanation for their rapid advancement in the past few years.
2 The emergence of CBDCs
We rst clarify how CBDCs may dier from physical cash. Figure 1 describes the taxonomy
of money. e digital form of a sovereign currency, a CBDC would be legal tender and fully
guaranteed by public authorities. is contrasts with deposits in commercial banks which
are guaranteed only in part: for example, €100,000 in the euro area and $250,000 in the US.
As legal tender, CBDCs could not be refused as means of payment or for repaying debts in the
respective jurisdictions.
However, legal tender laws are not sucient to guarantee the acceptability of a new cur-
rency, as shown in the literature (Lotz and Rocheteau, 2002). In a two-sided market, accepta-
bility comes not only from take-up by consumers, but also from take-up by merchants, who
must invest in the necessary equipment. is has been shown to be an obstacle and would
have to be addressed for CBDCs.
Also, CBDCs will be convertible one-to-one into other forms of central bank money –
reserve balances or cash. A CBDC will be the closest substitute possible to physical cash,
which settles near instantly. However, while the technology may be able to ensure privacy,
CBDCs will not allow for anonymity in the same way as physical cash. Last, holding CBDCs
would mean holding a direct liability with the respective central bank, very much like holding
a banknote.
摘要:

MariaDemertzis(maria.demertzis@bruegel.org)isaSeniorFellowatBruegelCatarinaMartins(catarinamartins@bruegel.org)isaResearchAnalystatBruegelExecutivesummaryDifferentjurisdictionshavesetoutdierentreasonsforcreatingcentralbankdigitalcurrencies(CBDCs).Somecountries,particularlythosewithalready-operation...

展开>> 收起<<
布鲁盖尔研究所-央行数字货币的增值:来自欧元区的观点(英)-2023.6-19页.pdf

共20页,预览6页

还剩页未读, 继续阅读

作者:Susu2024 分类:综合 价格:免费 属性:20 页 大小:528.19KB 格式:PDF 时间:2024-07-23

开通VIP享超值会员特权

  • 多端同步记录
  • 高速下载文档
  • 免费文档工具
  • 分享文档赚钱
  • 每日登录抽奖
  • 优质衍生服务
/ 20
客服
关注